PDA

View Full Version : How Currency Devaluation Affects Wealth by Henry C K Liu



blkrwssm24
07-06-2015,
By Henry C K Liu

In today's financial world, a liquidity boom produces rising nominal or face value in return on investment (ROI) with an increasingly hollow economy in two ways: (1) by devaluing all currencies against real assets and (2) by keeping down wages and worker benefits around the globe.

Thus while all currencies devalue steadily but not at the same pace, all of them devalue faster against real assets and slower against labor cost, because wage adjustments tend to lag behind both real and nominal inflation rates. This translates directly into low real valuation for labor, structurally constraining growth of demand to fall behind growth of supply. This in turn leads to an overcapacity economy of declining consumer purchasing power. Neo-classical economists call this the business cycle, which Keynesians assert must be countered with demand management through full employment supported by deficit financing.

The laws of overcapacity

The first law of overcapacity is that it is deflationary (falling market prices of assets), which in turn requires falling wages to maintain corporate earnings. The second law of overcapacity is that it discourages new plant expansion, so that existing capital assets appreciate in market value in nominal terms as liquidity increases, causing the stock markets to rise even though their economic value remains stagnant.

But the laws of overcapacity naturally lead to a downward economic spiral that ends in depression. Moreover, socio-political stability requires nominal wages to continue to rise above inflation. Thus the convenient monetarist solution is to allow stealthy but real devaluation of currencies against real assets, but with a slower devaluation rate against the value of labor.

The global regime of declining currency value is one that will lead to a new form of slavery, despite a rise in living standards from higher labor productivity and resource utilization as a result of technological progress.

Universal currency devaluation is masked by an exchange-rate regime in which currencies rise and fall unevenly against one another around the benchmark US dollar as the prime reserve currency, while all currencies fall against hard assets in unison but at different rates due to varying local conditions. The uneven rates of currency devaluation present windows of profit opportunity for arbitrageurs in the global foreign-exchange and financial markets. A network of interlocking asset bubbles then grows around the world as a result of dollar hegemony and the emergence of deregulated global currency and financial markets, jumping over national borders, fueled by a general devaluation of all currencies while the trading public is distracted to focus on the relative exchange value of one currency against another.

Thus while both the US dollar and the euro steadily fall, Europeans are comforted by seeing their currency rise against the dollar in recent years when in fact the euro has merely been temporarily falling at a slower rate than the dollar. As the dollar, the prime benchmark reserve currency for trade and finance, devalues against assets, the exchange-rate regime in the current international finance architecture will eventually drag all currencies down with the dollar, lest the trading partners of the United States find themselves saddled with trade penalties associated with inoperative exchange rates.

A confused public

The general public is further confused by uncertainty about whether a rising currency is good or bad for them. They are told to rejoice when their currency falls, as the goods they produce will sell in larger quantity because they can be bought with less money by foreigners, even their own income per unit of production will fall and they themselves will be crowded out of restaurants and shops in their own home towns by suddenly richer foreign tourists.

Ironically, while any normal citizen should find the prospect of receiving less money for the same amount of product he or she produces unappetizing, policymakers insist that there is no alternative systemically. In the meantime, the rich get richer from declining wages worldwide.

All the economies of the world are competing in global markets by pushing their domestic wages and worker benefits down in search of globalized "growth". The global market has turned into an arena for universal voluntary slavery to serve global capital.

BlaineTarr
07-07-2015,
Wicksell's ideas obsolete

Swedish economist Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell's idea of fighting inflation by pegging interest rates to ROI, operative under industrial capitalism, is problematic in finance capitalism because of the emergence of structured finance in which the traditional discounted rate of return for industrial investment tends to be overwhelmed by astronomical returns from financial manipulation routinely expected of hedge funds and private-equity firms.

To fight stealth inflation from currency devaluation, Wicksell's notion of pegging interest rates to ROI in structured finance would set interest rates so high as to make the sky-high rate of 19.93% under former US Federal Reserve chairman Paul Volcker pegged to money supply look tame.

Further, in Wicksell's time (he died in 1926 at the age of 74), there were no exchange-rate issues as there was no foreign-exchange market, since the reserve currency was based on the gold standard, with other currencies adopting fixed exchange rates against it. Cross-border movement of funds was strictly regulated, and currency accounts between trading nations were settled in gold regularly through adjustment of national accounts in the Bank of International Settlement.

Back then, domestic interest rates had no direct immediate effect on the exchange value of a country's currency. Today, domestic interest rates do have a bearing on currency exchange rates, albeit increasingly less directly. High domestic interest rates will push a currency's exchange rate upward, hurting a country's current-account balance and worsening domestic inflation, even though this relationship is increasingly obscured by the decoupling of nominal interest rates from the real interest rate and the decoupling of exchange rates between currencies from the real value of all currencies as derivative of a fiat dollar as the main reserve currency.

The lessons of 1987

The 1987 stock-market crash was unleashed by the sudden collapse of the safety dam of portfolio insurance, a hedging strategy made possible by the new option pricing theory advanced by Nobel laureates Robert C Merton and Myron S Scholes. Institutional investors found it possible to manage risk better by protecting their portfolios from unexpected losses with positions in stock-index futures. Any fall in stock prices could be compensated by selling futures bought when stock prices were higher.

This strategy, while operative for each individual portfolio, actually caused the entire market to collapse from the dynamics of automatic herd-selling of futures. Investors could afford to take greater risks in rising markets because portfolio insurance offered a disciplined way of avoiding risk in declines, albeit only individually. As some portfolio insurers sold and market prices fell precipitously, the computer programs of other insurers then triggered further sales, causing further declines that in turn caused the first group of insurers to sell even more stock and so on, in a high-speed downward spiral. This in turn generated other sell orders from the same sources, and the market experienced a computer-generated meltdown.

The 1987 crash provided clear empirical evidence of the structural flaw in market fundamentalism, which is the belief that the optimum common welfare is only achievable through a market equilibrium created by the effect of countless individual decisions of all market participants each seeking to maximize his own private gain, and that such market equilibrium should not be distorted by any collective measures in the name of the common good.

Aggregate individual decisions and actions in unorganized unison can and often do turn into systemic crises that are detrimental to the common good. Unregulated free markets can quickly become failed markets. Markets do not simply grow naturally after a spring rain. Markets are artificial constructs designed collectively by key participants who agree to play by certain rules. All markets are planned with the aim of eliminating any characteristic of being free for all operations. The free market is as much a fantasy as free love.

In response to the 1987 crash, the US Federal Reserve under its newly installed chairman, Alan Greenspan, with merely nine weeks in the powerful office, immediately flooded the banking system with new reserves, by having the Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC) buy massive quantities of government securities from the market. He announced the day after the crash that the Fed would "serve as a source of liquidity to support the economic and financial system". Greenspan created US$12 billion of new bank reserves by buying up government securities from the market, the proceeds from which would enter the banking system.

The $12 billion injection of "high-power money" in one day caused the Fed Funds Rate (FFR) to fall by 75 basis points and halted the financial panic, though it did not cure the financial problem, which caused the US economy to plunge into a recession that persisted for five subsequent years.

High-power money injected into the banking system enables banks to create more bank money through multiple credit-recycling, lending repeatedly the same funds minus the amount of required bank reserves at each turn. At a 10% reserve requirement, $12 billion of new high-power money could generatein theory up to $120 billion of new bank money in the form of recycled bank loans from new deposits from borrowers.

The Brady Commission investigation of the 1987 crash showed that on October 19, 1987, portfolio insurance trades in S&P 500 Index futures and New York Exchange stocks that crashed the market amounted to only $6 billion by a few large traders, out of a market trading total of $42 billion. The Fed's liquidity injection of $120 billion was three times the market trading total and 20 times the trades executed by portfolio insurance.

Yet post-mortem analyses of the 1987 crash suggest that though portfolio insurance strategies were designed to be interest-rate-neutral, the declining FFR was actually causing financial firms that used these strategies to lose money from exchange-rate effects. The belated awareness of this effect caused many institutions that had not understood the full dynamics of the strategies to shut down their previously highly profitable bond arbitrage units. This move later led to the migratory birth of new, stand-alone hedge funds such as Long Term Capital Management (LTCM), which continued to apply similar highly leveraged strategies for spectacular trading profit of more than 70% returns on equity that eventual led it to the edge of bankruptcy when Russia unexpectedly defaulted on its dollar bonds in the summer of 1998. The Fed had to orchestrate a private-sector creditor bailout of LTCM to limit systemic damage to the financial markets. The net effect was to extend the liquidity bubble further - it migrated from distressed sector to healthy sector.

The 1987 crash reflected a stock-market bubble burst the liquidity cure for which led to a property bubble that, when it also burst, in turn caused the savings-and-loan (S&L) crisis.

The Financial Institutions Reform Recovery and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) was enacted by the US Congress in August 1989 to bail out the wayward thrift industry in the S&L crisis by creating the Resolution Trust Corp (RTC) to take over failed savings banks and disposed of their distressed assets at fire-sale prices. The Federal Reserve reacted to the S&L crisis with a further massive injection of liquidity into the commercial banking system, lowering the FFR from its high of 9.86% reached on May 10, 1989, to 3% on September 4, 1992, making the real rate near zero until February 4, 1994.

It was too late to help president George H W Bush in his bid for a second term in the election of November 1992, but it gave the era of his successor, Bill Clinton, a liquidity boom. Since there were few assets worth investing in a down market plagued by overcapacity, most of the new money went into relatively low-yield bonds. This resulted in a bond bubble by 1993, which then burst in 1994 when the Fed finally started to raise the short-term rate, which reached 6% on February 1, 1995.

blbmvskf65
07-07-2015,
In the days of industrial capitalism, wealth was created by the creation of productive hard assets, while in finance capitalism, wealth is created only by earnings. Whereas wealth is increased by more production in industrial capitalism, earnings in finance capitalism increase only money income, which only adds wealth if the purchasing power of money does not decline. When asset prices rise without real expansion of the purchasing power of earnings, money is simply devalued, while the nominal value of assets increases as real wealth remains stagnant or even declines.

Initially, this flood of money that began in 1994 inflated another bond bubble, which popped viciously in 1999. Then, more liquidity released by the Fed boosted equity prices further and provided the fuel for the enormous tech-stock bubble of 1999 and early 2000.

The first three years of the 21st century saw a worldwide equity-market crash followed by a recession plagued by global overcapacity, over-indebtedness, and over-leveraging. And the response of central banks was always more liquidity through low interest rates in relation to return on capital, which helped pump up the bond bubble in 2003 and supported artificial rallies in housing prices, equities, commodity prices, higher corporate debt without changing debt/equity ratios, and mushrooming emerging markets, particularly China. Fools were calling it a US-led recovery.

A bubble within a bubble

Once the genie of excess liquidity is out of the bottle, it is almost inevitable that a bigger genie will have to be let out of a bigger bottle to keep the ongoing bubble from bursting, to avoid the nasty consequences of a burst bubble for the financial system and the real economy.

Central banks around the world, led by the US Federal Reserve, despite their pivotal role in helping to create financial bubbles, nevertheless declare that bubbles cannot be anticipated and nothing can be done to prevent them. But central bankers comfort markets by claiming magical power to handle the destructive consequences of bubbles, through a one-note monetary policy of short-term rate cuts to inject fresh liquidity, to save a bursting bubble by creating a bigger bubble. With structured finance, bubbles can be created by endogenous liquidity, and bubbles about to burst are expected by be rescued by central-bank intervention.

And even if central banks react to asset bubbles by raising short-term interest rates, the extent of the rate hikes needed to reverse asset prices in times of exuberance may be so large as to destabilize the real economy worse than a bubble burst would. This view is supported by the experience Greenspan had in his battle against "irrational exuberance".

While declaring that central banks cannot prevent bubbles, the Fed has admitted more than once that it sees as one of the roles of a central bank the support of the market value of financial assets, however inflated. Instead of being the guardian against moral hazard, the Fed has become the promoter of moral hazard.

A market anomaly is thus created in which equity prices rise in response to what normally would be considered bad news for the real economy, such as falling home sales, because the market then expects the Fed will lower short-term rates, causing equity prices to rise, even though home mortgage rates are tied to 10-year Treasuries rates. Conversely, equity prices can fall in response to what normally would be considered good economic news such as rising home sales because causes the Fed to raise short-term rates, which really do not have any direct connection to home finance. This is because the market knows that in a bubble about to burst, good news of further expansion is bad news.

US financial assets have been built not only on debt, but on debt recycled at high velocity. It is a form of turbo-debt, in which one dollar of debt can act as equity to finance more than $100 of credit through sequential leveraged financing and leveraged securitization. Borrowers in turn become lenders, who themselves lend borrowed money. Massive financial energy is released through chain reaction of a tiny amount of equity.

Debt is not intrinsically objectionable if it is adequately collateralized by real assets, and the proceeds are invested to increase real national income above what is needed to service the debt. But turbo-debt by definition is generated by practically no equity. And if debt is serviced mostly by the wealth effect of debt-propelled asset appreciation, a bubble is in the making.

So-called air-ball financing enabled the telecom bubble of the 1990s, when it was widely used in financing telecommunications expansion in the 1990s. Air-ball financing involves the use of unrealistically anticipated future earnings as collateral for financing overinvestments in hope of generating those earnings.

A housing bubble exists because houses are being financed and refinanced by full-value mortgages collateralized only by the anticipated continuing rise in home prices. A liquidity boom generates asset bubbles because liquidity is not wealth, only an illusion of wealth. And the rise in asset prices beyond the growth of gross domestic product is really a decline in currency value. A market rise of 40% against a GDP growth of 3% translates into a currency depreciation of 37% in a year.

Blurred distinction between debt and equity

The pervasive securitization of debt accompanied by a complex network of hedging blurs the all-important dividing line between debtor and creditor, and allows an economy to borrow from itself, not just against its future, but against its current and less sophisticated debt, not for productive investment to generate real wealth, but for financial manipulation to achieve virtual profit.

The use of debt as collateral for more sophisticated debt has characteristics of a bubble. The broad unbundling of risk to maximize transactional surplus (profit) ultimately leads to the socialization of risk (transferring unit risk into systemic risk), while the privatization of the resultant profit remains a sacred prerequisite. This maldistribution of virtual wealth exacerbates both the risk and the effect of a bubble by making a bubble inside a bubble.

The Bank of International Settlement's Lamfalussy Report defines systemic risk as "the risk that the illiquidity or failure of one institution, and its resulting inability to meet its obligations when due, will lead to the illiquidity or failure of other institutions". The prospect of systemic risk becomes commonplace when lenders are also borrowers who depend on the return of the funds they lent to pay for the sums they borrowed.

Risk of illiquidity, not any drop in demand for goods or loans, is the improvised explosive device (IED) of financial terrorism that puts in harm's way unsuspecting investors running a relay race on the debt-securitization treadmill.

Whether or when a bubble will burst depends on the central bank's ability to extend the bubble's elasticity, which is not unlimited, albeit flexible through inventive redefinitions of theoretical relationships and the cause-effect paradigm. To support the market, a central bank needs increasingly to intervene, which in turn destroys the market.

As is already apparent, the US Federal Reserve is increasingly reduced to an irrelevant role of rationalizing the virtual finance economy rather than directing it. It has adopted the role of a cleanup crew rather than the guardian of public financial health.

Ironically, a cure for a debt bubble can come from a bloodletting through asset hyperinflation, euphemistically called "unlocking value". In that scenario, the traditional strategy of holding cash gives no protection, because real currency value can fall faster than nominal asset-price depreciation. Such hyperinflation has brought down many governments and socioeconomic systems in history.

bkkazyjg11
07-08-2015,
High-yield spreads are tied to fundamentals such as expected future default rates. But spreads are also related to market liquidity in ways that are not yet well understood even by the most seasoned professionals.

Liquidity can disappear quickly

Liquidity, a fundamental concept relating to the quantity of money in monetary policy, can also be defined in the market as the ability to buy or sell large quantities of assets quickly and at low discount and cost.

Normally liquid assets can become illiquid in a market meltdown. The vast majority of equilibrium asset pricing models do not consider the effect of trading and thus ignore the time and cost of transforming financial assets into cash or vice versa, particularly in times of distress or exuberance, rational or irrational. Recent financial crises, however, suggest that, at times, market conditions can become suddenly severe and liquidity can decline or even disappear extremely quickly, even overnight or even in the middle of a trading day. Such liquidity shocks are a potential channel through which asset prices are influenced, or distorted, by liquidity.

In 1994, the bond market was caught on the wrong side of economic fundamentals and yanked down with the shifting tide of higher rates at the Fed. But stocks skated through relatively unscathed, because credit was still available and investors recognized that the bond market needed an adjustment that more accurately reflected the central bank's new thinking.

A bond fund's "duration" measures the theoretical impact that one percentage-point rise in interest rates would have on the net asset value of a fund. A bond fund with five-year "duration" could be expected to drop by 5% in value if interest rates rose by 1 percentage point. Conversely, a 1-percentage-point drop in rates would cause a fund with five-year duration to increase by 5% in value.

To figure total return, changes to net asset value (NAV) should be added or subtracted from the income generated by the fund. So a bond portfolio with a 3% yield whose NAV drops 5% would suffer a loss of 2% on a total return basis over a 12-month period.

Long-term bond funds often have effective durations of at least seven years. In that case, a rise in long-term interest rates of 2 percentage points over the next 12 months would cause at least a 14% drop in value. With yields on long-term Treasury bonds at 5%, such an increase would translate into a loss of 9% or more for fund shareholders - similar to when the Fed tightened monetary policy in 1994.

To protect against that possibility, investors keep fixed-income money in short-term corporate bonds, typically with durations of six months or less. With yields of long bonds below 5%, it would take a 9-percentage-point boost in short-term interest rates just to push the total return on such funds into the red over a one-year period. In the current environment of massive overcapacity and debt, the chances of that happening are about zero. That is why long bonds will rise as surely as tomorrow's sun.

Blaine Tarr
07-10-2015,
The lessons of 2003

In July 2003, Federal Reserve officials engaged in damage control after Greenspan spooked the bond market in congressional testimony by suggesting that the FFR at 1% might have fallen as low as it would go. Greenspan further disappointed investors by noting that the Fed was unlikely to engage in "unconventional" market activities, such as buying long-term government bonds to drive down long-term rates, which had stayed inverted for extended periods.

The policy of using interest-rate cuts to pump up demand has been tested to destruction since 1994. But all policies carry costs. The costs in this case included most obviously the dangers of pushing down long-term interest rates as well as short-term to a level that might be unsustainable, and subsequently reigniting inflationary pressures. In other words, the Federal Reserve was creating a bond bubble similar to the equity bubble, and then protecting the equity bubble by creating conditions where that bond bubble would be popped.

But investors that anticipated this scenario were fooled. Long-term rates stayed low because massive capital inflow came from foreign central banks operating under dollar hegemony. Bonds rose in 1994 further and faster than at any stage in the previous four decades, and collapsed in 1996 and again in 2003.

Once market participants think the market is turning against bonds through a rise in interest rates, they are likely to stampede out of bonds, creating a bond crash similar to the equity crash. Traders hedge their risk exposure in bonds with compensating positions in interest-rate futures by adopting immunization strategies by constantly rebalancing price risk with coupon reinvestment risk, which change in opposite directions.

In the 1950s, the bond market was considered a safe, conservative investment. At that time a buy-and-hold strategy was sufficient. However, since the 1960s, inflation has increased, and interest rates have become more volatile. Thus, with more volatile interest rates, there exists a greater profit potential with bonds. Also, the Macaulay duration, named after Frederick Macaulay, the introducer of the concept, being the weighted average maturity of a bond where the weights are the relative discounted cash flows in each period, came into use in the 1970s.

Under conditions of a liquidity boom, rising rates lower bond prices as well as equity prices. That combination is explosive enough, but adding to it the impotence of rising interest rates to halt the declining value of the dollar, we have a mixture of deadly financial dynamite that can be detonated by seemingly unrelated minor developments at unexpected times.

The psychosocial effect of a bond crash on market sentiment is highly damaging. Market participants and investors have been conditioned to think that lower returns on bonds are justified by their being less risky than equities. On a 30-year or longer basis, this is a correct view, but not on a three- or five-year term. Under current market conditions, there exists at least as large a possibility of 10-year bonds falling by 25% over any 18 months as there is of shares falling by the same amount. Yet investors in bonds do not have that same awareness of risk as equity investors, so the consequences could be serious. A typical portfolio with one-third in bonds will not escape losses in a bear market.